Skip to content

Commit

Permalink
Tom's first edits of June 18 in main repo
Browse files Browse the repository at this point in the history
  • Loading branch information
thomassargent30 committed Jun 18, 2023
1 parent c70d0b6 commit 87cadb9
Show file tree
Hide file tree
Showing 2 changed files with 99 additions and 79 deletions.
8 changes: 8 additions & 0 deletions lectures/_static/quant-econ.bib
Original file line number Diff line number Diff line change
Expand Up @@ -3,6 +3,14 @@
Note: Extended Information (like abstracts, doi, url's etc.) can be found in quant-econ-extendedinfo.bib file in _static/
###
@book{cochrane2023fiscal,
title={The Fiscal Theory of the Price Level},
author={Cochrane, John H},
year={2023},
publisher={Princeton University Press},
address={Princeton, New Jersey}
}

@incollection{sargent1982ends,
title={The ends of four big inflations},
author={Sargent, Thomas J},
Expand Down
170 changes: 91 additions & 79 deletions lectures/cagan_ree.md
Original file line number Diff line number Diff line change
Expand Up @@ -30,6 +30,11 @@ import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
<!-- #region -->
We'll use linear algebra first to explain and then do some experiments with a "fiscal theory of the price level".

A fiscal theory of the price level was described by Thomas Sargent and Neil Wallace in chapter 5 of
a 1981 article title "Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic". The theory has been extended, criticized, and applied by John Cochrane in {cite}`cochrane2023fiscal`.

In another lecture, we'll describe some historical episodes in which the elemental forces at work in the fiscal theory help to explain some early twentieth century hyperinflations that occurred in the wake of World War I.


According to this model, when the government persistently spends more than it collects in taxes and prints money to finance the shortfall (the "shortfall" is called the "government deficit"), it puts upward pressure on the price level and generates
persistent inflation.
Expand Down Expand Up @@ -368,6 +373,86 @@ This is because the reduction in $\mu$ at $T_1$ has been foreseen from the start
While the log money supply portrayed in the bottom panel has a kink at $T_1$, the log price level does not -- it is "smooth" -- once again a consequence of the fact that the
reduction in $\mu$ has been foreseen.
To set the stage for our next experiment, we want to study the determinants of the price level a little more.
### The log price level
We can use equations {eq}`eq:caganmd` and {eq}`eq:ree`
to discover that the log of the price level satisfies
$$
p_t = m_t + \alpha \pi_t
$$ (eq:pformula2)
or, by using equation {eq}`eq:fisctheory1`,
$$
p_t = m_t + \alpha \left[ (1-\delta) \sum_{s=t}^T \delta^{s-t} \mu_s + \delta^{T+1-t} \pi_{T+1}^* \right]
$$ (eq:pfiscaltheory2)
In our next experiment, we'll study a "surprise" permanent change in the money growth that beforehand
was completely unanticipated.
At time $T_1$ when the "surprise" money growth rate change occurs, to satisfy
equation {eq}`eq:pformula2`, the log of real balances jumps
**upward* as $\pi_t$ jumps **downward**.
But in order for $m_t - p_t$ to jump, which variable jumps, $m_{T_1}$ or $p_{T_1}$?
### What jumps?
What jumps at $T_1$?
Is it $p_{T_1}$ or $m_{T_1}$?
If we insist that the money supply $m_{T_1}$ is locked at its value $m_{T_1}^1$ inherited from the past, then formula {eq}`eq:pformula2` implies that the price level jumps downward at time $T_1$, to coincide with the downward jump in
$\pi_{T_1}$
An alternative assumption about the money supply level is that as part of the "inflation stabilization",
the government resets $m_{T_1}$ according to
$$
m_{T_1}^2 - m_{T_1}^1 = \alpha (\pi^1 - \pi^2)
$$ (eq:eqnmoneyjump)
By letting money jump according to equation {eq}`eq:eqnmoneyjump` the monetary authority prevents the price level from **falling** at the moment that the unanticipated stabilization arrives.
In various research papers about stabilizations of high inflations, the jump in the money supply described by equation {eq}`eq:eqnmoneyjump` has been called
"the velocity dividend" that a government reaps from implementing a regime change that sustains a permanently lower inflation rate.
#### Technical details about whether $p$ or $m$ jumps at $T_1$
We have noted that with a constant expected forward sequence $\mu_s = \bar \mu$ for $s\geq t$, $\pi_{t} =\bar{\mu}$.
A consequence is that at $T_1$, either $m$ or $p$ must "jump" at $T_1$.
We'll study both cases.
#### $m_{T_{1}}$ does not jump.
$$
\begin{align*}
m_{T_{1}}&=m_{T_{1}-1}+\mu_{0}\\\pi_{T_{1}}&=\mu^{*}\\p_{T_{1}}&=m_{T_{1}}+\alpha\pi_{T_{1}}
\end{align*}
$$
Simply glue the sequences $t\leq T_1$ and $t > T_1$.
#### $m_{T_{1}}$ jumps.
We reset $m_{T_{1}}$ so that $p_{T_{1}}=\left(m_{T_{1}-1}+\mu_{0}\right)+\alpha\mu_{0}$, with $\pi_{T_{1}}=\mu^{*}$.
Then,
$$
m_{T_{1}}=p_{T_{1}}-\alpha\pi_{T_{1}}=\left(m_{T_{1}-1}+\mu_{0}\right)+\alpha\left(\mu_{0}-\mu^{*}\right)
$$
We then compute for the remaining $T-T_{1}$ periods with $\mu_{s}=\mu^{*},\forall s\geq T_{1}$ and the initial condition $m_{T_{1}}$ from above.
We are now technically equipped to discuss our next experiment.
#### Experiment 2: an unforeseen sudden stabilization
Expand All @@ -390,7 +475,7 @@ To capture a "completely unanticipated permanent shock to the $\{\mu\}$ process
that emerges under path 2 for $t \geq T_1$ to the $\mu_t, \pi_t$ path that had emerged under path 1 for $ t=0, \ldots,
T_1 -1$.
We can do the MIT shock calculations entirely by hand.
We can do the MIT shock calculations mostly by hand.
Thus, for path 1, $\pi_t = \mu_0 $ for all $t \in [0, T_1-1]$, while for path 2,
$\mu_s = \mu^*$ for all $s \geq T_1$.
Expand All @@ -399,7 +484,7 @@ We now move on to experiment 2, our "MIT shock", completely unforeseen
sudden stabilization.
We set this up so that the $\{\mu_t\}$ sequences that describe the sudden stabilization
are identical to those for experiment 1, the foreseen suddent stabilization.
are identical to those for experiment 1, the foreseen sudden stabilization.
The following code does the calculations and plots outcomes.
<!-- #endregion -->
Expand Down Expand Up @@ -523,17 +608,17 @@ ax[2].plot(T_seq, m_seq_1 - p_seq_1,
ax[2].set_ylabel(r'$m - p$')
ax[3].plot(T_seq, m_seq_2_regime1,
label=r'Unforseen (Insist on $m_{T_1}$)')
label=r'Unforeseen (Smooth $m_{T_1}$)')
ax[3].plot(T_seq, m_seq_2_regime2,
label=r'Unforseen (Reset $m_{T_1}$)')
label=r'Unforeseen ($m_{T_1}$ jumps)')
ax[3].plot(T_seq, m_seq_1,
label='Foreseen shock')
ax[3].set_ylabel(r'$m$')
ax[4].plot(T_seq, p_seq_2_regime1,
label=r'Unforseen (Insist on $m_{T_1}$)')
label=r'Unforeseen (Smooth $m_{T_1}$)')
ax[4].plot(T_seq, p_seq_2_regime2,
label=r'Unforseen (Reset $m_{T_1}$)')
label=r'Unforeseen ($m_{T_1}$ jumps)')
ax[4].plot(T_seq, p_seq_1,
label='Foreseen')
ax[4].set_ylabel(r'$p$')
Expand All @@ -550,79 +635,6 @@ plt.show()
+++ {"user_expressions": []}
### The log price level
We can use equations {eq}`eq:caganmd` and {eq}`eq:ree`
to discover that the log of the price level satisfies
$$
p_t = m_t + \alpha \pi_t
$$ (eq:pformula2)
or, by using equation {eq}`eq:fisctheory1`,
$$
p_t = m_t + \alpha \left[ (1-\delta) \sum_{s=t}^T \delta^{s-t} \mu_s + \delta^{T+1-t} \pi_{T+1}^* \right]
$$ (eq:pfiscaltheory2)
At time $T_1$ when the "surprise" regime change occurs, to satisfy
equation {eq}`eq:pformula2`, the log of real balances jumps
**upward* as $\pi_t$ jumps **downward**.
But in order for $m_t - p_t$ to jump, which variable jumps, $m_{T_1}$ or $p_{T_1}$?
### What jumps?
What jumps at $T_1$?
Is it $p_{T_1}$ or $m_{T_1}$?
If we insist that the money supply $m_{T_1}$ is locked at its value $m_{T_1}^1$ inherited from the past, then formula {eq}`eq:pformula2` implies that the price level jumps downward at time $T_1$, to coincide with the downward jump in
$\pi_{T_1}$
An alternative assumption about the money supply level is that as part of the "inflation stabilization",
the government resets $m_{T_1}$ according to
$$
m_{T_1}^2 - m_{T_1}^1 = \alpha (\pi^1 - \pi^2)
$$ (eq:eqnmoneyjump)
By letting money jump according to equation {eq}`eq:eqnmoneyjump` the monetary authority prevents the price level
from **falling** at the moment that the unanticipated stabilization arrives.
In various research papers about stabilizations of high inflations, the jump in the money supply described by equation {eq}`eq:eqnmoneyjump` has been called
"the velocity dividend" that a government reaps from implementing a regime change that sustains a permanently lower inflation rate.
#### Technical details about whether $p$ or $m$ jumps at $T_1$
We have noted that with a constant expected forward sequence $\mu_s = \bar \mu$ for $s\geq t$, $\pi_{t} =\bar{\mu}$.
A consequence is that at $T_1$, either $m$ or $p$ must "jump" at $T_1$.
We'll study both cases.
#### $m_{T_{1}}$ does not jump.
$$
\begin{align*}
m_{T_{1}}&=m_{T_{1}-1}+\mu_{0}\\\pi_{T_{1}}&=\mu^{*}\\p_{T_{1}}&=m_{T_{1}}+\alpha\pi_{T_{1}}
\end{align*}
$$
Simply glue the sequences $t\leq T_1$ and $t > T_1$.
#### $m_{T_{1}}$ jumps.
We reset $m_{T_{1}}$ so that $p_{T_{1}}=\left(m_{T_{1}-1}+\mu_{0}\right)+\alpha\mu_{0}$, with $\pi_{T_{1}}=\mu^{*}$.
Then,
$$
m_{T_{1}}=p_{T_{1}}-\alpha\pi_{T_{1}}=\left(m_{T_{1}-1}+\mu_{0}\right)+\alpha\left(\mu_{0}-\mu^{*}\right)
$$
We then compute for the remaining $T-T_{1}$ periods with $\mu_{s}=\mu^{*},\forall s\geq T_{1}$ and the initial condition $m_{T_{1}}$ from above.
#### Experiment 3
Expand Down

0 comments on commit 87cadb9

Please sign in to comment.